Some historical and global examples of tax resistance → France → tithe resistance

James C. Scott, in a paper in the Copenhagen Papers series (“Everyday Forms of Resistance,” ), looked at tax resistance as one of the varieties of behind-the-scenes peasant resistance to exploitation.

In particular, he investigated resistance to mandatory tithing of rice yields in Malaysia. This tithe was a traditional Islamic zakāt that had been made mandatory and brought under the control of the central government in 1960, in the course of which the government also added an invasive bureaucracy that “mandated the registration of acreage and yields in order to enforce its collection.”

Says Scott:

Opposition to the new tithe was so unanimous and vehement in the villages where I conducted research that it was a comparatively simple matter to learn about the techniques of evasion. They take essentially four forms. Some cultivators, particularly small-holders and tenants, simply refuse to register their cultivated acreage with the tithe agent. Others underreport their acreage and/or crop and may take the bolder step of delivering less rice than even their false declarations would require. Finally, the grain handed over is of the very poorest quality — it may be spoiled by moisture, have sprouted, be mixed with straw and stones so that the recoverable milled grain is far less than its nominal weight would suggest.

Scott says that the government, in one local sample, got only one-fifth of the grain that it would have if people had complied with the tithe law. But though this was a largely successful tax strike, it was also a quiet one:

There have been no tithe riots, no tithe demonstrations, no petitions, no violent confrontations, no protests of any kind. Why protest, indeed, when quieter stratagems have achieved the same results at minimal risk? …it is the safer course for resisters to leave the tithe system standing in name while they dismantle it in practice… without affording the state an easily discernible target. There is no organization to be banned, no conspiratorial leaders to round up or buy off, no rioters to haul before the courts — only the generalized non-compliance by thousands of peasants.

Scott says that there are three factors that aid this mode of resistance:

  1. “a palpable ‘climate of opinion’ ” — that is, a widespread belief that the tithe is unjust and that resistance is proper
  2. “a shared knowledge of the available techniques of evasion”
  3. “economic interest” — that is, the fact that it is personally economically advantageous to resist paying the tithe

(He refines this in another work to: “the conjunction of a folk culture that encourages some forms of resistance, a set of habits and practices that are part of the practical heritage of the peasantry, and a shared material interest in thwarting appropriation [that] can produce a form of tacit coordination that mimics or substitutes for formal organization.”)

Also important is the political context. The authorities could, Scott says, crack down on evasion, though this would be costly and difficult. But it would also hurt political support for the ruling party among the peasantry.

Scott says that once tax resistance “has become a customary practice it generates its own expectations about what is permissible [and] raises the political and administrative costs for any regime that subsequently decides it will enforce the rules in earnest. For everyday resisters there is safety in numbers and successful resistance builds its own momentum.”

He also notes, in another context, that “the social historian could profitably examine the role of petty tax resistance in producing, over time, the ‘fiscal crisis of the state’ which frequently presages radical political change. Here too, without intending it, the small self-serving acts of thousands of petty producers may deprive a regime of the wherewithal to maintain its ruling coalition and prevail against its enemies.”

In another paper (“Resistance without Protest and without Organization: Peasant Opposition to the Islamic Zakat and the Christian Tithe,” 1987), Scott compared the Malaysian zakāt resistance to earlier resistance to mandatory Christian tithing in France, in support of his thesis that…

…a vast range of what counts — or should count — as peasant resistance involved no overt protest and requires little or no organization.

This look at what Scott calls “everyday resistance” is in reaction to our normal tendency to concentrate on more organized, visible, acute uprisings and to consider other forms to be inchoate, immature forms of real rebellion. Because the duration of and the number of participants in such everyday resistance may be greater than of more well-recognized revolts, their effect on the balance of power between the ruling class and the exploited class may be proportionally greater as well.

By itself, the peasantry’s most common and durable weapon is an everyday resistance that stops short of the more dangerous forms of overt protest and confrontation.

Because members of the exploited class lack access to the legislative and administrative levers of power, they take their political stand instead at the point of enforcement. As Thoreau put it:

I meet this American government, or its representative the State government, directly, and face to face, once a year, no more, in the person of its tax-gatherer; this is the only mode in which a man situated as I am necessarily meets it; and it then says distinctly, Recognize me; and the simplest, the most effectual, and, in the present posture of affairs, the indispensablest mode of treating with it on this head, of expressing your little satisfaction with and love for it, is to deny it then.

Scott gives a pleasant oceanographical metaphor about this sort of resistance:

Everyday resistance does not throw up the manifestos, demonstrations, or pitched battles that normally compel attention. It makes no headlines. But just as millions of anthozoan polyps create, willy-nilly, a coral reef, so do thousands of individual acts of insubordination and evasion create a political and economic barrier reef of their own. There is rarely any dramatic confrontation, any movement that is particularly newsworthy. And whenever, to pursue the simile, the ship of state runs aground on such a reef, attention is typically directed to the shipwreck (for example, a fiscal crisis) itself and not to the vast aggregation of petty acts that made it possible.

The paper goes into more detail about the Malaysian resistance, and shows how effectively the peasants essentially set their own tax rate rather than complying with the official one. When improvements in irrigation allowed the rice farmers to plant two crops instead of one during the course of a year, which officially subjected them to twice the tax, they instead “simply compensated by paying less than half of what they paid earlier on a single crop.” Collectively, they reduced a nominal 10% tax to an actual 1.5% one.

Scott then looks at the French tithe resisters in the light of this. He notes some overt, acute resistance (“In , the residents of one commune refused to pay the wine tithe and threatened to throw the collector into the Rhône. In , another village, led by its curé, stoned the monks and their tithe agent when they came to collect the grain. In , peasants wearing disguises sacked the granary of the tithe collector, and no witnesses could be found to testify against them.”), but is more interested in the “everyday resistance,” finding that in France the techniques “were far more elaborate and varied.”

These techniques included:

  • introducing novel crops or growing marginal ones that were not covered by existing tithe laws
  • growing taxable crops alongside or interspersed with non-taxable ones and then claiming the whole field as exempt
  • opening new, hidden plots of land to planting without declaring them
  • planting tax-exempt “gardens,” “orchards,” or “meadows” that were functionally equivalent to taxable fields
  • harvesting and hiding a portion of the crop before the tax collector arrived
  • assembling sheaves in such a way as to conceal valuable grain in the non-taxable base
  • taking advantage of the rounding-off process in counting the grain to make large portions of the harvest effectively exempt

Much of this is simply clever loophole-hunting, aided by a culture of tax disgust that celebrates and spreads it. Each technique alone was a petty nuisance to the tax-gatherers, but in the aggregate they took a huge bite out of their cut — one complained “of thirty sacks, it is plausible that they pay only one.”

This individual, canny, shoulder-shrugging, “who, me?” resistance was made possible by “a generalized, often unspoken complicity… the French sources frequently refer to ‘tacit consent,’ ‘unanimity,’ the refusal to give testimony, and conspiracies of silence.”


I gave some examples of attacks directed at tax offices, I gave some further examples of attacks on the apparatus of taxation, and I gave some examples of how some tax resistance campaigns used particularly humiliating violent attacks against individual tax collectors to deter them and discourage their colleagues.

Today I’ll give some further examples of terrorism and intimidation directed at tax collectors — this time by means of attacks on their homes and property.

  • Bailiffs, the officials responsible for seizing goods from Poll Tax rebels in Thatcher’s Britain, were targeted in this way. In one case, the home of a bailiff company’s chief was surrounded by protesters, who, finding that the target of their protest was not at home, “had a look at his double garage — the door was open. … Well, there wasn’t a car inside, but there was a mountain bike, fishing tackle, clothes, bottles of wine, garden equipment. In fact, the place was chock-a-block. A mock auction was held in front of the press. Anyway, his possessions ended up strewn all over the garden, and slogans were daubed across the back of his wall: ‘Fuck off bailiff, we’ll be back!’ The police arrived about five minutes after we had gone. We heard that Mr. Roach [the bailiff company chief] was escorted home later that night in a police car. It’s good to give people like that a taste of their own medicine.”
  • “a party of armed men in disguise made an attack in the night upon the house of a collector of revenue who resided in Fayette County, but he happening to be from home, they contented themselves with breaking open his house, threatening, terrifying, and abusing his family.”
  • This tactic was used frequently during the Rebecca Riots in Wales, for example:
    • “A plantation belonging to Timothy Powell, Esq., of Pencoed (a magistrate active against Rebecca), was fired… and four acres were burnt.”
    • A crowd of some 7–800 Rebeccaites surrounded the home of tithe collector Rees Goring Thomas and fired guns through the windows at the terrified occupants. “[P]arts of the walls were so thickly marked with shots and slugs that scarcely a square inch was free from them, while the windows and curtain were thickly perforated… There were in all fifty-two panes of glass broken in five windows. … While these outrages were carried on at the house, several of the mob forced open the door, and entered the beautiful walled garden adjoining the house, where they committed devastations of a most disgraceful character. Nearly all the apple trees and wall-fruit trees of different kinds, were entirely destroyed, being cut to pieces or torn up from the roots. The various plants and herbs with which the garden abounded were all destroyed, and a row of commodious greenhouses, extending from one side of the garden to the other, was attacked, and a large quantity of glass broken with stones.”
    • That same crowd then attacked the home of a game warden, firing a blank directly into the face of his wife. “They then broke the clock, a very good one, an old pier-glass which had been handed down for several generations, the chairs, table, and all the little furniture the poor people possessed. They also carried away the gamekeeper’s gun, and 10s. or 12s. worth of powder and shot, and previous to leaving took from the drawers all the clothes of the family, which were torn, trodden upon, and partly burnt. They then left the place, after firing several times. Several of the painted doors, leading from the road to the plantation, were destroyed by the Rebeccaites.”
  • During the French Revolution, in Baignes, the home of the director of the excise “is devastated and his papers and effects are burned; they put a knife to the throat of his son, a child six years of age, saying, ‘Thou must perish that there may be no more of thy race.’ ”
  • In , French tithe resisters “wearing disguises sacked the granary of the tithe collector, and no witnesses could be found to testify against them.”
  • In Naples, in , “the populace began to attack the houses of those whom they knew had, by farming tolls or in any other way, become rich at the expense of the people. … [T]he houses were emptied: first that of the cashier of taxes, Alphonso Vagliano. Beautiful household furniture, plate, pictures, everything that could be found was dragged into the streets, thrown together in a heap and burnt; and when one of the people wanted to conceal a jewel, he was violently upbraided by the rest,” because the point was terroristic vandalism, not looting. “All the rich and noble persons who were concerned in the farming of tolls, as well as all members of the government, saw their houses demolished. … Above forty palaces and houses were consumed by the flames on , or were razed to the ground…”
  • During the French Gabelle Riots of mobs roamed the streets setting fire to tax collectors’ houses.”

If your tax resistance is motivated largely by a desire to take resources away from the government, or to reduce the amount that people provide resources to the government, then it may not matter to you so much whether the means of accomplishing this are illegal civil disobedience or merely legal tax reduction strategies. For this reason, some tax resistance campaigns have included a pragmatic tax education component. Here are some examples:

  • During a sales tax strike in Ontario in , the accounting firm Deloitte Haskins and Sells Canada (an ancestor of today’s enormous Deloitte professional services firm) published a booklet that described several ways that people could legally avoid the sales tax: “The booklet includes such tips as buying large children’s clothing for small-sized adults or buying baby skin care products as substitutes for adult versions.”
  • In the tax resistance group from Oregon called “Peace Investors of Eugene” conducted counseling sessions on illegal tax resistance options, but also two clinics “to tell people how they can legally reduce the amount of federal income tax they have to pay.”
  • For several years, I participated in the Volunteer Income Tax Assistance (or VITA) program, which enlists ordinary people like you and me to help people — typically people with low incomes — fill out their income tax returns. The program is sponsored by the IRS, which trains the volunteers in tax preparation. The great majority of returns filed through the program result in refunds rather than additional payments (at a ratio of about 15:1), and so by volunteering I was able to take money from the government and give it back to tax filers.
  • Another war tax resister and tax preparer, John Hammar, remarked in that “If every resister just had one or two times [the amount of] their own taxes kept away [from the government] by helping others cut their tax bills, our efforts would then become a factor in the national budget.”
  • In , a writer for the Friends’ Intelligencer advised readers how to structure their estates and bequests so as to avoid the “United States ‘war tax’.”
  • French farmers in used (and shared among themselves) every legal trick they could discover (and several less legal ones besides) to reduce or eliminate the tithes due on their crops: for instance by growing new crop varieties that were not contemplated by the tithe laws, and planting “gardens” or “orchards” or “meadows” that were exempt although functionally equivalent to the taxed fields.