How you can resist funding the government → arguments against tax resistance → Ricardo Rodríguez

There has been a lot of talk of tax resistance in Spain lately, both from an energetic war tax resistance movement and from a new environmental / social justice tax resistance campaign focusing on the skulduggery of the Spanish government’s responding to the economic crisis with corporate bailouts.

Now the backlash begins. Ricardo Rodríguez of Rebelión pens the following left-wing critique of tax resistance (translation mine):

Critique of Tax Resistance

1.

Everyone knows that Spring customarily brings the flowering of the gardens, the heat of love, and the obligation to submit your tax returns — all equally arousing things, though in different erogenous zones. For some years at this time there have also tended to be some social organizations spreading their campaigns for so-called tax resistance, simultaneously with the tenacious clerical propaganda for good Catholics to mark the box on their tax returns next to the Catholic Church. The comparison is not an idle one, for we see that this and the other campaign agree on the same economic formula, a formula that is in my opinion alarmingly reactionary, even in the view that it is with the best, most altruistic and noble intentions in the world.

The way in which it tries to encourage citizens to object via taxes, and the method that it proposes for doing so, may vary in some details, depending on the organization or the social platform in question, but always they repeat some elemental features. The manifest and indisputable injustice is alleged in which the state always dedicates fewer resources to sustaining basic public health and education services, or to the aid of the most disadvantaged social classes, directing instead exorbitant amounts to armaments, heavily polluting industries, or to various other ends damaging to the community. Most common is tax resistance that is justified in protest against military spending, but this is not the only possibility. This year, for example, in particular: the opposition to the transfer of billions in public money to banks and the real estate sector, among other principle causes of the crisis, which without a doubt constitutes an obscenity.

The concrete objection is to refuse to pay, when submitting the income tax return, a particular amount of money that beforehand will be redirected to some social organization that struggles for peace, for social justice, or for conservation of nature. The amount usually is small, fixed, calculated as a percentage of the tax or freely determined by the “objector.” As a fixed amount, 84 euros has been proposed, which is meant to symbolize the 84 most impoverished countries on the planet. And the choice of a percentage of the tax is singularly comical, because it supposes that in general those who owe more taxes are freed from paying more to the Treasury, or, seen another way, that the right to resist grows in proportion to the wealth of the taxpayer — a strange notion of economic justice to be promoted by leftist groups.

The most common formula for reflecting this reduction we withhold from our taxes consists in simply recording it in the blank box of miscellaneous deductions or subtracting it from the tax owed. In one way or another, if what is intended is to express a protest, it must be sufficiently visible, not camouflaged in some concept that could be easily overlooked. It is recommended for this reason that the Tax Administration Agency be contacted with a written statement, claiming that we deduct the money from our return in order to reduce military spending (or from nuclear plants, or public bank bailouts, or all at the same time), and that a receipt is attached showing our redirection to a social organization or project that we have chosen.

Let it be clear that I am in heartfelt agreement with the idea of fighting for public funds to be allocated to guarantee quality social services for all citizens and to reduce inequality and fight injustice. The question is whether tax resistance helps these objectives, as such, and if not, on the other hand, what other harmful side effects might follow.

After submitting our tax return with the corresponding act of civil disobedience, two things may happen. It is to be expected that the Tax Agency will issue its own return and charge us for what we failed to pay. For this eventuality, the promoters of resistance ask us to comfort ourselves until the end with the idea of converting each such letter into a new opportunity to protest (a protest, indeed, that will stop in the hands of some bureaucrat who typically ignores our pleas for social justice, and who will simply dismiss our claims according to the stipulated procedure). It will be useful to clarify to the potential resisters of good faith how much more influence they can have with their protest letters the more money they owe. Above all, one should note that the social advocacy organizations for tax resistance usually include themselves among the beneficiaries of the redirected money and that it is obligatory to observe a minimum of honesty with our purveyors. In any case, in the best scenario, we will be charged the debt plus interest. Although one thing to know, having announced our unequivocal will to not submit part of the tax, knowing that legally we have to, the General Tax Law does without a doubt cover such a case with sanctions for non-compliance. On the other hand this usually does not come to pass.

It happens in no few occasions, however, that the Tax Agency makes no complaint. In an article published recently in favor of resistance, I read the pious explanation that the motive for such indulgence might be that small amounts are not detected, or because of bureaucratic negligence or even “complicity.” In reality, things don’t work like this. In practically all tax returns, missing income is detected by computer (except for sneaky tax shelters that show no evidence of irregularity, a practice that would contradict the intention to use the tax resistance as a public protest). And if once discovered but not charged, this is likely because the debt is so low that the administrative procedures to force payment would cost more, or because, given the growing scarcity of personnel, the Tax Agency offices are concentrating on larger debts. I feel, indeed, this betrays a trust in the existence of bureaucrats sympathetic to our cause, but I can perhaps dream that there are many willing to risk their jobs overlooking procedures that are strictly regulated, concerning things in which each decision remains recorded and personally keyed in databases, and that are accounted with a multitude of controls, as well as being audited with relative frequency.

From one motive or another, often we settle with ourselves and pay less than we owe to the Treasury. What have we achieved with this? Only to reduce, by much or little, the amount of State revenue. After which, the government will allocate a sum of what is collected to such expenses as it decides, and not to those which objectors have demanded, and, as for having to reduce some part, it will be in that which seems good. A government that realizes a conservative economic policy — and, frankly, I do not hope for another type of government, at least in the coming years — will tend just to sacrifice social spending, and, in each case, will always meet their obligations to the army, to NATO, to the large corporations, and to the banks. If to do so one has to sacrifice spending on health or education, so be it. To be successful, our good-intentioned tax resisters might take note of the segments of society least protected by underfunded public services. We have given our money to committed social organizations, it is true. But these, as diligent as they are, will always constitute a private safety net. That is to say that we may be provoking a transfer of resources from universal, free, public services to private entities. This is a form of privatization, or, in other words, transforming the exercise of rights that we have demanded from the powers that be, into charity dependent on good samaritans. James Petras has given us some excellent texts on this, not much to the taste, of course, of certain NGOs.

2.

One might think, however, that although tax resistance lacks any effect on revenue and public spending or even has somewhat undesirable effects, it might, to compensate, set off a social echo of rebellion against the patent injustices of the capitalist state. But an examination of the results of all the tax resistance campaigns of the past years would have to have disillusioned the proponents on this point by now. Nobody would have learned that such campaigns are carried out if not for the publicity that the same promoting social organizations give. And, of course, the letters sent to the Tax Agency have absolutely no effect. In general, bureaucrats pass over such arguments of a political nature when resolving appeals; at most, they remember it as an anecdote of their work. The mythical vision of dozens of senior Administration officials terrorized by the exemplary valor of tax rebellion is a puerility that has nothing to do with the real world.

However, if the mere exercise of tax resistance is not significant or symbolic, the spread of the campaigns may serve up to the people a vision of taxes that has a surprising neoliberal resonance.

To begin, we have to question if it is very leftist, or even progressive, to claim the right of every citizen to decide individually what the state must do with the revenue from their taxes. For to go even further: if we imagine a society that has superseded capitalism — socialist, communist, or libertarian — do we proclaim as a right for every person to dictate to the community the particular destination of their contribution? Is this what the hell they mean when they allude to the objective of making every citizen “master of his income tax?” Of what character of economic democracy are we thinking — the same as Milton Friedman and Hayek? Doesn’t it address the collective management of the wealth of society? Or am I old-fashioned? To what point has the destruction of economic thinking reached that the left approaches these matters without a hint of doubt remaining?

Basically, fundamentally, what the partisans of resistance claim is the same as what serves the Catholic Church when it claims a slice of the income tax, as I said at the start. The Episcopal Conference and the denominational Spanish state offer fervent citizens the opportunity to, in conscience, direct a percentage of their tax contribution to the unpaid pastoral work of don Rouco Varela. And the partisans of resistance claim that the same possibility exists for antimilitarists or for those who hate the looting of the country at the hands of the bankers. In those last two groups, I include myself. The problem is that, when someone asserts a political right with universal character, it must take into account that not all of the citizens are going to make the same use of it, and admit, nevertheless, that any use will be legitimate. Many of us will object to military spending and will redirect our portion of savings to progressive organizations, but others will want to subtract what is invested in the public health to practice abortions with dignity and security for women, or from unemployment payments, or will even desire for that military expenses increase, as showing patriotism can also be a subject of conscience. Who will decide, and with what criteria, how far the conscience of each one can reach? And since Emilio Botín is just as much a citizen as us, he will be granted the corresponding right to object, and not only that — if he decides to use the formula of a percentage of his tax, his right will be infinitely larger than that of his gardener.

Consistent with individualism as the model of society that underlies the acceptance of tax resistance, is the individualism of resistance as a civil rights issue in which the right to object is recognized as the Law. The means are adjusted faithfully to the end proposed in this case, as what happened with the first Jesuits. I mean to say that, in the current configuration of the income tax in our country, tax resistance as protest can only be an act eminently individual and moreover elite, or at least not equal for everyone.

It is a fiction that we pay our income tax at the moment of presenting our tax return; this is not so. In reality, in the months of May and June the only thing that we do is submit to the Treasury a final accounting of what we have been paying over the past year for all of our income. Salaried workers have paid their tax every month via the tax withholding that has been taken from their pay. And small business owners and contractors make quarterly payments to account for what they have self-assessed in each period. It is very difficult to practice tax resistance if one’s tax return comes back with a refund; but that it comes back with a refund doesn’t mean that one hasn’t paid ones income tax, but that in the final balance more was contributed to the Treasury and one asks that it refund the surplus. Even if one is self-employed and files and has no right to a refund — a situation in which we find each year thousands of citizens, incidentally those with the lowest incomes — still objection is entirely impossible, despite, as with the previous case, that one has paid ones taxes religiously. Not to mention the poorest citizens, unemployed, retired, or social outcasts, whose taxes, or absolute lack of them, they do not give or have withheld, who do not pay income tax but many other sales taxes far more unjust than the income tax, each time they buy bread, board the bus, or eat soup, from which they are not given benefits.

All these thousands of people remain excluded from the possibility of tax resistance. Which is to say, we speak of a “right” that business, individual or corporate, can exercise with the greatest of ease, but that salaried employees, retirees, and the unemployed will find very difficult if not impossible. In olden times, a right of this nature was called privilege. We are to believe in the sincerity of the social organizations that assert the right to object, but the truth is that what they ask for is an economic option that can be enjoyed principally by the upper classes, in which I don’t find many enthusiasts for world peace, or proponents of reduction in military spending, or those furious about public money used for bank bailouts.

In certain educational pamphlets from the promoters of tax resistance are proposed resolutions to this problem in the form of the curious suggestion that those who don’t submit a tax return instead send letters asking for the recognition of the right to object. Very elegant: that the poor may be in solidarity with our responsible economic action as peaceful middle-class citizens. Also propose that, along with everything else, they come together with us in defraying the interest on the tax debt if the Tax Agency reclaims it from us. This, in order that they may feel they too have accomplished something, you see.

It’s very significant, for that matter, that the objection proposed happens to concern the income tax, one of the few taxes in our country — and almost the only one — that preserves some trace of progressivity, although increasingly more limited with each successive reactionary tax reform approved in these two decades by the People’s Party governments along with those of the Socialist Party. At least since Marx and Engels included the requirement of “strong progressive taxation” in one of the ten major proposals for social transformation in the Communist Manifesto, the labor movement has attached great importance to the existence of high and very progressive income taxes in order to achieve social justice.

Why not, for example, a social mobilization against paying VAT on the purchase of food and other articles of crucial necessity? Why not search for solidarity with small businesses in performing symbolic actions of sale without VAT? It’s been about a century since Rosa Luxemburg wrote, in her work The Accumulation of Capital, a concise but visionary chapter showing the social and economic relation of the revenue from indirect and sales taxes with militarism. The artificial increase of prices that provoke consumption taxes will cause a diversion of productive resources to one sector, the military, in which big business can solve its problems of insufficient markets by guaranteeing demand via political decisions of the state and transforming war itself into a specific region for accumulation. Rosa Luxemburg offered data that give suspicion that this was what happened in the years immediately before the outbreak of the first world war. Maybe it would be better to reflect on the reactionary tax reforms and today’s wars and to see if we can do something about it, if we want to, as antimilitarists, if we are to be taken seriously.

3.

I will acknowledge, in conclusion, that temperamentally I am very skeptical about proposals for what is called conscientious objection. I have never proposed as my principal goal for my social action to bring peace to my conscience but to change reality to make it less odious. I don’t want that I should be aloof from injustice, but that injustice not be committed. While I remain alive, I can’t stand aside. I don’t aspire that what I pay as my income tax does not go to military spending or to aid for bankers and speculators, but that military spending not increase and that aid not be given to bankers and speculators. And neither do I seek after a society in which I have the right to decide the destiny of my contributions to the community. My ideal is a society in which everyone and all who create the common wealth decide collectively how to manage it, in order to make true the principle of “from each according to his ability and to each according to his need.” That would only be viable if it destroys capitalism, clearly, and if the capitalist state is transformed into a network of people’s councils that allow for every public decision to be adopted in a democratic and free manner by all citizens.

Those who share a similar ideal, though it be far off, have to agree at least that the actions that we take to achieve it have to be essentially collective and to move towards it and not in the opposite direction.

In the daily struggle, the forms of intervention can be many. With a simple act of joining some fifty people at the Tax Agency in Madrid on the first day of tax season to protest against the wars and the complicity of the state with the looters of the country, it is possible to appear on all of the televisions and to make an impact on public opinion much greater than all the tax resistance campaigns. On occasion it has been done. The most profound and stable way — not detracting from the organization for a citizen’s movement to demand a just and progressive tax system, that which includes a recognized principle in Article 31 of the Constitution of 1978, stubbornly flouted with all the others that don’t suit the masters of the nation. It is not very hard to explain to the citizenry the intolerable injustice of a dual-track income tax, in which one pays much more on earned income then on income from capital, or how the progressivity of taxation has been forcibly reduced in the past decades. We must denounce those who benefit from the suppression of taxes on capital and the constant rebates of corporate taxes, and unmask the land-owners who again requested raising the VAT rates. We tend to think that taxes are too dry a subject to organize social movements around, even though they constitute the backbone that sustains the set of social services before which privatization revolts us with reason.

With the actions of the struggle can coexist on occasion, of course, the civic refusal to pay certain taxes, either because they are unjust or because in extreme situations we decide to break with any variety of collaboration with the state and face the risk of receiving the corresponding punishment. In this last consists the true civil disobedience, that we ought never to trivialize because it is something too serious. I recall from the novelist Norman Mailer in his book The Armies of the Night, that the movement against the Vietnam War in the United States included, as a gesture of disobedience in solidarity with the burning of draft cards, a refusal of taxes. The idea was to challenge the state and declare oneself in complete rebellion before it until the withdrawal from Vietnam and the end of the murder of innocents. In the United States tax system, an action like this could be very visible because, unlike in our own in which the public administration concentrates its measures on collecting tax debts and the amount of tax crime is very high, there the consequences of not paying usually means winding up in jail. In such a way, authentic acts of tax rebellion are always treated, and not merely objection that aspires to be recognized by the system as a peaceful variety. It has nothing to do with some ridiculous poseur in the style of the bandit Fendetestas in El Bosque Animado. Nobody can protest against imperialism and the massive crimes of the system and then merely be satisfied with pilfering small change from the purse.

When certain citizens have committed radical acts of civil disobedience, of deep ethical and political significance, they have been able to run grave personal risks if there existed an energetic, organized movement that supported them and even had sufficient strength to challenge power. It is evident that today is not the point at which such western societies can be found, although with the indecency and the extent of the robbery, in a country with more than four million unemployed, one would think that we would live over a social volcano. However, this does not have to paralyze us.

How have we not put into place a broad-based campaign to propose to people that they pull their savings from the banks? Something that would be entirely legal, but that would truly shake the pillars of the system and that would probably stun more than one, even should we not bring many people on board right away. If we’re talking about civic opposition, with effective measures, to the delivering of billions of public money to Botín, let’s let him clear from the government the money that they have given, we are going to withdraw. How have occupation actions not spread to bank branches? In a meeting of social movements in 2006 at Complutense University in Madrid, economist Fernando Urruticoechea proposed encouraging property owners to sell, in order to stimulate the replacement of home ownership for renting, but also to cause a collapse in the housing market in order to unblock the infernal and corrupt economic platform that churned our national capitalism. If memory serves, among the social organizations that today make audacious apostleship for tax resistance are those that did not look kindly on this initiative.

There are many ways to oppose the iniquities of the world, many, save that of making a virtue of necessity and hiding our failures under the versatility of private conscience.

All of this has mostly confirmed for me that liberals are annoying the whole world over. That’s probably too hasty. Rodríguez and I just don’t start with the same assumptions is all.

If I believed, as he does, that people have a duty to contribute to the public good (as defined by whoever happens to be making decisions for the public), he would be right that I would be hypocritical to complain about my tax dollars not being spent on things I approve of, and he would be correct to warn me of the terrible implications of letting non-politically-correct people have the same rights of conscientious tax objection that I claimed for myself.

If I believed, as he does, that individualism and assertions of conscience are the tools of an evil neoliberal agenda, then I might heed his warning about the anti-collectivist assumptions behind conscientious objection.

As I don’t share these points of view with Rodríguez and the left/progressive audience he’s writing for, most of his arguments are lost on me. What remains is some critique of tax resistance as being largely ineffective and based on exaggerated assumptions about its influence on those in authority (which I suppose I can grant on some level), being more likely to result in reduced government spending on “the good stuff” than “the bad stuff” (which distinction impresses me less than he might think in any case), and being elitist to boot.

The elitism charge is because income tax resistance is an option mostly available to people who have enough income to owe income tax and who are in the relatively privileged position of not having income tax automatically deducted from their paychecks. Rodríguez bristles at the idea that those who owe more taxes can resist more taxes, which makes tax resistance a sort of “regressive” activism, I guess, that the rich can buy more of than the poor.

This strikes me as ludicrous. Of course, from the point of view of the resisters, a rich person isn’t getting away with more resistance by having more to resist so much as he is more badly complicit in the government’s misdeeds if he doesn’t resist and redirect, and so he has a stronger obligation to do so than most. Quite the opposite from what Rodríguez infers. And the idea that tax resistance is bad because it isn’t a universally-available option is just as silly. It’s like telling people they shouldn’t burn their draft cards because women and the elderly would be unable to fully participate in such a protest. (Notably, the protests Rodríguez himself champions — withdrawing your savings from banks and selling off your real estate — seem if anything even more susceptible to his “elitism” critique.)

Most challenging to me was Rodríguez’s attitude towards conscientious objection in general. He sees conscientious objection as a narcissistic substitute for effective political action:

I have never proposed as my principal goal for my social action to bring peace to my conscience but to change reality to make it less odious. I don’t want that I should be aloof from injustice, but that injustice not be committed. While I remain alive, I can’t stand aside. I don’t aspire that what I pay as my income tax does not go to military spending or to aid for bankers and speculators, but that military spending not increase and that aid not be given to bankers and speculators.

In this, Rodríguez is a sort of utilitarian anti-Thoreau. Thoreau was the great champion of conscientious objection — it’s not my duty, he said, to end injustice, but I must not myself behave unjustly:

It is not a man’s duty, as a matter of course, to devote himself to the eradication of any, even the most enormous wrong; he may still properly have other concerns to engage him; but it is his duty, at least, to wash his hands of it, and, if he gives it no thought longer, not to give it practically his support. If I devote myself to other pursuits and contemplations, I must first see, at least, that I do not pursue them sitting upon another man’s shoulders. I must get off him first, that he may pursue his contemplations too.

But although I’m about as Thoreauvian as they come, I admit that Rodríguez’s position also has its attraction. I do sometimes feel the narcissistic pleasure of polishing up my conscience in the privacy of my own soul and then taking it down from the shelf from time to time to admire it some more, and at the same time I recognize that my opinion of my own conscience is of no value to anybody but myself, and nothing good can come of such a pastime but only reckless pride and stupid self-satisfaction.

It is good to have clean hands, but there are better things to do with them than to admire them.

But it’s not as though Rodríguez, with his more utilitarian approach, were thereby immune from self-satisfaction. It’s not as though he can think, “I am willing to debase myself, to take on horrible moral burdens, if this is what it takes to make a better world.” I’m sure he sleeps well with his approach too, and has just as many opportunities to pat himself on the back. Truth is, I’m much more suspicious of the kind of self-congratulation I might engage in if I thought I was doing whatever-it-takes in pursuit of noble utilitarian ends, than I am about the dangers of an ascetic and aloof self-regarding virtue in the Thoreauvian mold.


, I shared Ricardo Rodríguez’s critique of tax resistance from Rebelión. Also , Rebelión published a rejoinder from Pablo San José of “Turtle Antimilitarist Group” (translation mine):

In defense of War Tax Resistance

I have read, with some surprise, an article published on the Rebelión website and signed by Ricardo Rodríguez — Critique of Tax Resistance.

In said paper is found a broad (but intended to be detailed) and harsh critique of this political tactic. It is not the first time that people — a priori, and not based on our ideas and practices — have made such fratricidal criticisms, and coincidentally a little conveniently at the time of year during which the campaign is made, and of course Ricardo Rodríguez is not the first person to raise these same arguments.

Although Rodríguez says there exist different ways to do “tax resistance,” as one who has spent years working on this within the Antimilitarist Movement, I will try to defend the particular form which we call “war tax resistance” by responding to the criticisms made.

I will try to summarize in five points the principal criticisms that emerge from Rodríguez’s long paper:

  1. Tax Resistance is elitist and reactionary, inasmuch as it is proposed in one of two formulas: a taxpayer redirects a particular percentage of his taxes, such that one who has more money has “freed himself from paying the Treasury more money,” “the right to object increases in proportion to the wealth of the taxpayer.” That, he indicates, is a “strange notion of economic justice to be promoted by groups on the left.” On the other hand, the most precarious citizens who are not obligated to file, or whose tax return results in “a refund,” etc. become unable to effectively practice it. “Employers, but not the employees” may object, which makes it a privilege and an absurdity insomuch as these elites are not going to be particularly interested in disarmament or in other social improvements.
  2. The redirection of money that is to be done via Tax Resistance does not work toward the pursued goal. The state will not apply this reduction in revenue to the ends proposed by the resisters, but to whatever it finds convenient. And in the present context, this will be most likely to rebound negatively on expenses for social security and not on those for the military, banks, etc. In fact, we could be contributing to worsening conditions of the least advantaged sectors of society.
  3. Following the previous argument is put forward as a possible response that “still, in any case the money will overflow to social necessities, since it is to this type of destination that the resisters redirect,” and he shoots this down with the argument that such a thing represents “a transfer of resources from free, public, universal services to private entities,” to “a private safety net,” to “the charity of good Samaritans” who usurp the right that we have to receive such benefit from the “powers that be.”
  4. The supposed symbolic function of Tax Resistance to serve as a tool to transform consciences is stopped in its tracks. The results of the campaign speak for themselves. Moreover, the campaign is only known thanks to the efforts of its own promoters. The letters sent to the Tax Agency managers, he affirms, are completely lacking in political significance.
  5. The campaign generates an ideology with neoliberal resonance: it proposes that the payment of taxes can be something decided by individuals and not by the collective “necessity” determined by the “state” or by some type of authority that looks out for the common interest. Such a thing is very dangerous as from it could derive the right of each individual to oppose contributing to whatever he is not in agreement with, putting the question of financial contributions to the common good on a somewhat objectively slippery slope (do we accept the right of pro-lifers to object to health spending, or Emilio Botín to social policies?).

I would very much like to talk about the base assumptions underlying these questions in the article from Ricardo Rodríguez, such as the nervousness that freedom understood as an individual right appears to produce in him, his faith — that I deduce from reading between the lines — in the “democratic centralism in the Leninist style” as a model of organizing collective decision-making, his commitment to state institutions as the supreme guarantee of the public good and the ultimate manager of of the rights that they permit, or his antagonism to “Conscientious Objection,” which he ends up fancying as reducing to a species of individual moral scruple, ignoring or wanting to ignore everything about the political, public, and transformative dimensions. However I will not enlarge unnecessarily on this already very extensive response, and I will limit myself to commenting on the arguments related to the topic under debate.

From reading Rodríguez’s text it can be deduced that he does not speak from hearsay and possesses plenty of knowledge with respect to the mechanics of Tax Resistance and of the aspirations pursued by the entities that promote it. However there are evidently also important lacunæ and deficits of focus.

War Tax Resistance, which is the concrete example to which I will refer, is not an end in itself, nor does it intend to detract from antimilitarist work (much less the anti-imperialism of which Rodríguez speaks), nor do those who promote it proclaim it to be the definitive or unimprovable tool.

In fact most of the groups that promote it emerged from and participate in the larger antimilitarist/pacifist movement, working for decades simultaneously on other types of work such as what was, back in the day, Draft Resistance, promotion of a curriculum for peace education, direct action against military installations, counter-propaganda, etc., etc. In reality, it is not even a campaign in and of itself, but is part of the larger work we call “Campaign against Military Spending” and which includes more time, resources, and actions each year.

The immediate and realistic object of this proposal is not to overthrow the military by means of the method of depriving it of financial resources. Rodríguez should not imagine us to be so naïve. We would like that such a thing could be, but for now it suits us to avail ourselves of this gesture — that, as noted, is more symbolic than effective today — in order to amplify our protest, that is against military spending, but also against the institution that is dedicated to this spending, and to its use at the service of certain interests that in the final analysis are those of the capitalist economic system. Yes, Rodríguez, with this work, to your eyes elitist, reactionary, neoliberal, and — why not say it? — counterrevolutionary, “politically infantile” and petit-bourgeois, we try, just like you, to combat and transform the capitalist system.

War Tax Resistance helps very many people every year — fewer than we would like but more than what would be if we were not to put forth the effort — become aware of the fact of the matter of militarism in this society and to learn concrete data concerning its importance and omnipresence, its causes and consequences… and in particular data about the way the public treasury dedicates money to these purposes and not to others.

Rodríguez says (point 1) that tax resistance is elitist and reactionary: “with the most spending power, more money can be diverted…” That is one way of looking at it, but you must know that the how-much-money question is the least important in the campaign. The truth is that we hardly pay attention to the amount of money that is redirected each year. What interests us is the number of resisters. We are just as happy if they have redirected a percentage of their tax, or the particular amount of 84 euros, or half a euro, or… a resistance of three thousand euros (which there is) has no more political value than one of ten cents. Besides being mistaken on this question, it is possible to perform War Tax Resistance, and so we recommend, when your tax return results in a refund, when your tax is zero, or when one does not legally need to file. It is not true that poor and unemployed people cannot participate, in fact they do participate according to most resisters. On the contrary, and as is natural, there isn’t much participation from “the elites.”

With respect to the second argument (point 2), that the state will subtract the money that it fails to collect from the budget for social purposes, it is but the subjective presumption of Rodríguez. In any case, people who make this gesture add force to their communication so that the politicians and the rest of society will be conscious of our desire that this money not be financing armies, armaments, and wars. If such a demand is ignored, the responsibility clearly has to be imputed to those who disobey the popular mandate and not to us, as Rodríguez aims to accuse. And effectively — and this is a question of political strategy — the bureaucracies in service to the System may, as is often the case in other times and areas, ignore the citizens’ desires and demands and act illegitimately, but everything has its limit. I am convinced that in this case the limit is quantitative. If resisters represent a small percentage of the population, they may amount to nothing, but at the moment when they present a significant figure, it will not be so easy to deal with them.

The approaches that I have outlined in point 3 look to me a bit out of place as they seem to reflect a very particular political ideology. There is no time to waste in questioning here the faith of eurocommunists and some Leninist groups in the “Welfare State” and in the “State as guarantor of services, rights, and liberties,” and diametrically opposite, in a Manichean way, is all that is not “State,” conceived of as “privatization, Samaritanism” and other such monsters. It is a point of view that seems to me tendentious and reductionist. To compare solidarity organizations that receive money from War Tax Resistance with capitalist enterprises in search of profits and without social utility, I believe is totally excessive, and to proclaim that such social assistance provided by the state will be better than any alternative, seems the same.

In fourth place, according to my summary, Rodríguez questions the extent of Tax Resistance. Here I must submit to reason. Certainly it is only the efforts of the promoting groups that gives part of society access to the political message that is hoped to transmit. Unfortunately, the mass media tend to ignore the campaign, with some honorable exceptions. Indeed, Rodríguez proposes alternative actions such as gathering before the tax agency doors at the beginning of tax season, actions for that matter — as he acknowledges — we are accustomed to do. Perhaps it is our responsibility that the work of War Tax Resistance has a limited scope. But even if it is a solid argument against it, I don’t believe that this alone can dismiss it. There are struggles that last a long time in bearing fruit; and while they go on with no significant results they come to affect the way many people see things, and, in this case, as I say all the time, this is no more than a part of a larger work, it’s complementary. However, as things are, and to look at it from another point of view: what revolutionary political struggle today is making an end of the System? That would not lead us to come to the conclusion that none of those existing have validity and sense.

Finally, the fifth point of the summary brings us to a disquisition of an ethico-political sort. The principal determinant of the actions of each of us is what: individual conscience or collective agreement? Rodríguez sticks with the second; me with the first. And in fact I believe that the collective agreements must be fabricated, and then applied, by means of the free consent of personal choice and not some type of victory of majorities over minorities. Because being the majority is not synonymous with being right, and because our individual conscience — this concept that appears to have so little credit with Rodríguez — is that which makes us people and not pieces of machinery. Neither do we agree in the value we give to the institution of the State as administrator and arbitrator of rights. That’s why he didn’t issue, for my part, enough skepticism at this time about the possibility of people of different ideologies refusing to pay taxes. In the transformative and revolutionary horizon, which unfortunately for now we are far from as Rodríguez points out, until a society without the State, without accumulation of power or of wealth, in which people can be really free and interact with dignity and justice, it is reasonable to neglect to pay part of or all of the taxes to the actual administration, as it is reasonable not to have a big problem with other people, the way things are, doing the same.

I should not neglect to refer to a couple of inaccuracies in Rodríguez’s text, to wit:

It is to be expected that the Tax Agency will issue its own return and charge us for what we failed to pay. For this eventuality, the promoters of resistance ask us to comfort ourselves until the end with the idea of converting each such letter into a new opportunity to protest

Though Rodríguez appears to not be familiar with it, some years back the opposite was recommended. This is a symbolic political gesture that works in the face of the arousal of the society, it is not masochism or an act of martyrdom. This path of appeal is only recommended with certain conditions, and if it will be used effectively as a means of protest to amplify the denunciation of military spending, knowing full well that the appeal may not technically succeed in a legal sense, except for those relating to fines.

And if once discovered but not charged, this is likely because the debt is so low that the administrative procedures to force payment would cost more, or because, given the growing scarcity of personnel, the Tax Agency offices are concentrating on larger debts.

This argument only applies with respect to tax returns with tax owed, but in the many in which the result is a refund and the Treasury refunds what it has to, then is refunding more via the WTR, how do you explain that?

Finally I strongly call attention to the suggestions that Rodríguez made with his possible alternatives (that are no improvements) to Tax Resistance.

  • On the one hand, he calls out for tax resistance to indirect taxes (the VAT, etc.) in place of the “very revolutionary” — according to Marx and Engels — progressive taxes like the income tax. Indirect taxes, according to Rosa Luxemburg, increase the capability to finance militarism.
  • Also, inconsistent with the previous in my view, he proposes to refuse paying direct taxes in certain cases that he judges to be more legitimate. For example, he cites the refusal of some Americans to pay taxes on such grounds during the Vietnam War. Such a gesture is considered by Rodríguez as “true civil disobedience” while that of War Tax Resistance is entitled “denouncing imperalism and the massive crimes of the system and then merely being satisfied with pilfering small change from the purse.”
  • Finally, a sort of uprising called anti-bank actions à la Enric Durán, represents something like the true way to proceed.

In conclusion:

This criticism doesn’t seem to me very pleasing, and less at this particular time of the year. If Ricardo Rodríguez is a revolutionary activist so conscious of the necessity of overthrowing the capitalist system, why don’t present realities occur to him as more worthy of criticism and denunciation than this? Even assuming he were right in all or in part of his critiques, could War Tax Resistance really present an obstacle so capital as to warrant such an onslaught? And along with the questions, does Ricardo Rodríguez wander so lazily in his revolutionary work that he does not have another thing to aim against than those who, with methods more or less far from his, work for a similar objective?

One is to believe that Ricardo Rodríguez is an active member of one or various revolutionary collectives and that they take themselves seriously at this — than many people promoting War Tax Resistance and who back in the day performed Draft Resistance — in the front of the struggle that he considers more useful and practical. However the current reality, that there are not many struggles going on that appear to be seriously undermining the System, must give us a certain humility and a certain consideration for the work of others. Because it does not seem that the Leninist parties in their various guises are anywhere near the point of winning elections, nor does it appear that any massive anti-bank movement is at the point of achieving a financial collapse.

But, because we believe in humanity and have hope, we continue forward.

In any case, thanks also for the chance to reflect, assess, and take stock of what is involved in this public critique.


The debate continues! These translations take me hours, as my Spanish is so rudimentary, so I don’t know how much longer I can keep up. Especially as the argument seems to be descending into hot, dark, flame war territory at this point (in this latest dispatch Rodríguez seems to mostly be restating the points in his first one, but in a heightened tone of indignation).

But anyway, here Ricardo Rodríguez responds to Pablo San José’s rejoinder to Rodríguez’s critique of tax resistance (translation mine):

Clarifications concerning tax resistance

Pablo San José has had the courtesy to respond to my critique of the tax resistance campaigns in an article that appeared, like mine, in Rebelión.

I would like to make some clarifications, with the promise that I will not bore readers with a new essay on this same subject:

  1. The finding that I have poorly chosen the time for my writing, given that we find ourselves in the midst of tax season, depends, naturally, on what is your opinion about tax resistance. Mr. Pablo San José would have to admit the possibility that there are those who are not in accord with it, and that, for those who think thusly, tax season is the most opportune moment to express what they think.
  2. It would be healthy some time for us to begin to respond without referring to prejudices of individual taste. As Don Pablo San José is not pleased by what I think, he pigeonholes me without reservation in the group that advocates “democratic centralism in the Leninist style” or, alternatively, in the camp of “eurocommunism” and those who have a blind faith in the State. Thereby I am grouped in the company of evil, making it much easier to continue your article drawing on the categories of “us” (the things we do, the risks we take, the antimilitarists) and “them” (the sectarian communists who do nothing and are limited to censuring the actions of others). Polemicizing in this way is very simple, but is not honest.
  3. In no place in my writing do I equate the organizations that develop projects of social aid with private for-profit enterprises. I said it constitutes a “private safety net.” Depending on the case, not only do I admire such but have personally collaborated in it with my work, but I do argue that what we must aspire to is that the management of social services be public, because this is the only way to provide them with a guarantee of full justice and universality. It is commendable that there are groups of people disposed to mitigate the suffering of other human beings, but the ideal is that the community be collectively addressing the needs of everyone. My goal is that the State comes to vanish and be substituted by assemblies of citizens who take the fundamental decisions with the free and considered participation of all. To the extent that we are fighting for this utopia, the privatization of public services does not appear to me as the best road to take.
  4. Concerning the question of elitism, I must have explained myself poorly and I will try to correct myself now:

    In a number of writings favorable to tax resistance that I have read, I have encountered two aspects related logically to each other. On the one hand is proposed an act of symbolic struggle against the militarism and other injustices of the system. On the other hand, is demanded that the right to object be recognized by Law as a civil right. But, clearly, when one requests to be able to exercise a right it is assumed that one is disposed to admit that others can exercise it with purposes different from yours, and when someone suggests a form of protest, it should give provision for what serves for other objectives when others see that it is a valid form of protest.

    Probably, Pablo San José is ignorant that there are other tax resistance campaigns, in particular one that promotes an important policy of the Catholic Church in opposition to abortion. You can find information about it at http://www.arbil.org/100fiscal.htm. I, as Pablo San José imagines, am a die-hard enemy of militarism and a partisan, on the other hand, of the right of women to make free decisions about motherhood; under no opinion are the ends of the two campaigns comparable. But the means is the same and the right that is claimed is to be able to carry out both. And truly in a democratic society that allows tax resistance, why can a citizen not claim that with “his” income tax payment public health practice of abortion is not to be funded? In fact, it is sufficiently improbable that the State will go so far as to admit that one may resist military spending, but it is not outrageous to imagine that, within their regulatory capacity, regional governments such as that of Madrid introduce at one time or other an option such as for abortion. In such a case, your movement has put forward an essential part of this argument’s arsenal.

    And here is where we touch on the core that Pablo San José mentions but on which he did not want to elaborate: individual liberty. In no place do I oppose it. That which I question is whether one can have the option to decide individually what the whole community can do with that which he contributes. I said, and I repeat, that such a claim is reactionary. If tax resistance became a recognized right, it would be economic capability that would determine the ability to have influence over collective decisions, and then we would not be facing a society of free and equal individuals. The absence of real democracy in the modern capitalist states must be overcome with the collective force of socially organized citizens, as much for a Leninist as for a follower of the beautiful ideas of Kropotkin. And if that is the goal, the methods are to point towards it, and not in the opposite direction. This is what I said.

    In regard to the concrete practice of resistance as a form of protest I also ought to explain something. I did not write that those who receive a refund are unable to resist, but that for them it is more difficult. Neither did I say that it is impossible for those who are not obligated to file, but that for such people the result of filing will not be a refund. It would be absurd for a person not obligated to file to file a return to pay (something that Pablo San José will know is not infrequent), put forward the income tax to pay that which he is not obligated to pay, and subtract the quantity for the resistance. Come on now, I say. And then I mentioned people so poor that they don’t pay income tax, independently from their obligation to file, but who pay a multitude of consumption taxes every day. That about “the more purchasing power, the more money can be redirected” (I did not use those words, so I don’t understand the quotation marks), was referring only to when the percentage-of-the-tax formula is used. I imagine that this latter will not be denied: whether or not the quantity is more important, it is mathematics that if you resist a percentage, in general the people with higher taxes will fail to pay more to the Treasury.

    But, to sum up, this again does not rebut the fundamental question, which is whether the power to protest or to decide be based on ones economic capacity, such that it would lock out from participation a particular number of citizens, perhaps a thousand or three million. Because of this, I think that it is elitist, it is the end that will come from the right to resist being legalized, and it is the means, because the means have adjusted to the ends. Authoritarianism is not the road to freedom, and economic exclusion is not the road to equality.
  5. San José notes two inaccuracies in my article. He says, firstly, that it is not true that in at present it is recommended to appeal to the bitter end if the tax agency demands the unpaid amount. I am happy to be able to correct my error on this point, but I must clarify that an article published this week in Kaos en la Red and taken from the Diagonal speaks of continuing “with the protest, appealing to such demands (those from the tax agency) until exhausting all of the legal avenues”, without advancing prevention of the unfavorable consequences. By coming in one of the publications promoting resistance, I supposed that the information was correct.

    Secondly, San José asks for an explanation why in some tax returns with refunds the tax agency refunds the expected amount plus the resisted quantity. Well, the explanation is the same as that for tax returns where money is owed. The large-scale control of the correction of tax returns is computerized. There are a series of filters. Most of them are cross-checked with information provided to the agency by third parties, also filtered by increasing of the amount, or specific filters (for example, statements of death always contain information for claiming accreditation documentation of the endowment of the heirs from whom they charge a refund). If no computer filter catches the mismatch, from the low quantity or because it appears in an entry that does not conflict with any third-party data, the process continues its course: the tax return is validated without parallel output or recourse whether it is for a payment or a refund is requested. Only the returns flagged by the system are reviewed by staff and there isn’t an individual decision from a bureaucrat for each of these returns. But then, if Mr. San José wants to continue thinking of other possibilities, he may do so.
  6. I’m not going to add more (and I have had enough already) about the proposals I protest. I get the feeling that I have not been understood very well, that historical allusions have been mixed in with that which I propose today, or the simple act of removing money from a bank account (an legal act that in principle carries no legal risk) is equated with the action of Enric Duran (that in fact I have supported).

    That which concerns me more is the small importance that appears to be given to taxes on the left. In this area, the ideological defeat is overwhelming. It may be said that a consumption or indirect tax that all citizens pay is equal with a tax that can have an effect on redistributing the wealth; that we don’t mind that great estates avoid tax, or that it carelessly brings us the incessant rewarding of the corporations with deductions from social security tax. I don’t say anywhere that the income tax is revolutionary; I say it is one of the few taxes that conserve some progressivity, and that if we choose to begin a campaign of protest with reasons legitimate in principle, it would be more careful that we do not give ammunition to our adversary for tightening the screws on the path to economic inequality. Of that there is more than enough, unfortunately.

    To me it seemed that this was sufficient reason to waste my insignificant time in offering my opinion. I have under my belt nearly twenty years of political and social militancy, collaborating in diverse campaigns, confident that not in this will I cede to Pablo San José. Always I give my opinion with sincerity and admit that I may be wrong. But never have I tolerated from anyone, nor am I going to tolerate, that I am required to selflessly toe the party line in order to have the right to do so. Neither will I, for my part, require that from anyone else.